Debunking the Myth of “Sham Elections” in the Middle East
In this year’s Iranian presidential election, the victory of the moderate candidate, Masoud Pezeshkian, suggests a high level of dissatisfaction with the conservative government, especially on economic and social issues. As such, the election is a good example of how domestic factors – and the domestic economy in particular – often play a decisive role in elections in the Middle East, just as they do elsewhere.
A November 2023 article in The Economist, titled “The Middle East Faces a Series of Sham Elections”, characterises political regimes in the region as collectively consumed by an authoritarian sclerosis that renders them immune to any possibility of change via electoral institutions. “The elections will be farcical”, the piece declares. “Results are decided in advance.” The authors of this piece are by no means the first to make this claim: for decades, scholars and other observers have puzzled over why non-democratic regimes choose to hold elections, one core component of procedural democracy. While an earlier strand of this literature frames such elections as mere performance or “window dressing” for the regimes that hold them, a robust scholarly literature actually finds exactly the opposite.For decades, scholars and other observers have puzzled over why non-democratic regimes choose to hold elections In short, elections even in less-than-democratic contexts can promote intense political competition that sometimes brings about unexpected changes in the composition and power of the ruling elite.
The beyond-symbolic significance of elections under authoritarianism has been amply demonstrated by several elections held in 2024 throughout the Middle East. Various national elections (this piece will refrain from discussing local/municipal races) held in the region this year also demonstrate the wide variation in how elections shape regimes across different non-democratic contexts. While September’s presidential elections in Algeria, for example, may come the closest to The Economist’s “sham” descriptor – characterised by widespread fraud, low participation rates, and near-total repression of opposition actors – other 2024 elections are not so straightforwardly contrived, either in process or outcome. In Iran and Jordan, presidential and national legislative elections (respectively) earlier this year were characterised by intense competition and, ultimately, the empowerment of longstanding opposition (broadly defined) movements and actors.
Moreover, these elections and the surprising results they brought cannot be explained solely through the lens of macrostructural change – i.e., the ongoing and increasingly regionalised conflict in Gaza, or the effects of the United States and Western Europe’s sanctions regime on Iran. Instead, the interplay between these structural factors, on the one hand, and the agency of domestic opposition and regime actors, on the other, provides a more complete and nuanced understanding of why elections matter, even when they are not “free and fair” by conventional standards.
Iran’s Presidential Elections: Surprising Reformist Victory
Iran held two rounds of presidential elections in June and July 2024, following the death of former President Ebrahim Raisi in a helicopter crash in May. Iran’s elections at the presidential and legislative levels are frequently competitive, but far from fully “free and fair” – the appointed Guardian Council vets candidates and has ultimate discretion over whether they are allowed to run, and this mechanism has been frequently used since the inception of the Islamic Republic in 1979 to bar opposition or reformist candidates from seeking office. In the 2024 elections, for example, only six out of 80 candidates who registered for the presidential race were allowed to run.
Despite this clear violation of democratic principles, the six candidates who ran in Iran’s June elections represented a wide array of ideological positions, ranging from several conservative “hard-liners” (e.g. Saeed Jalili and Mohammad Ghalibaf) to more reformist or “moderate” candidates, chiefly Masoud Pezeshkian, who was backed by a variety of pragmatic reformist groups. The first round of elections produced a runoff between Jalili and Pezeshkian, while the second round resulted in higher turnout rates and, ultimately, a victory for the reformist camp, led by Pezeshkian.
Pezeshkian’s victory came after three years of conservative rule under former President Raisi, which coincided with both an economic downturn and widespread anti-government protests following the death of Mahsa Amini in 2022. Elections, even under severe constraints like those in Iran’s institutional setup, provide a potent, if limited, vehicle for public expression As such, his win can be interpreted as a clear public rebuke of conservative leadership on a range of economic and social issues. But more significantly, his victory demonstrates that elections, even under severe constraints like those in Iran’s institutional setup, provide a potent, if limited, vehicle for public expression. This also helps make sense of why non-democratic regimes like Iran’s would risk holding elections in the first place – they allow elites to “take the temperature” of the public and recalibrate accordingly.
Jordan’s Legislative Elections: Surge in Support for the Islamist Opposition
Such temperature-taking also recently happened in Jordan, a monarchy where competitive elections also regularly occur. Unlike in Iran, candidates in Jordanian legislative elections are not vetted by the regime, but elections there are frequently subjected to allegations of vote-buying and fraud – all occurring within a context where freedom of expression and collective action are severely limited. In other words, different but important constraints also exist on electoral institutions in the Jordanian context.
With that said, the September 2024 legislative elections in Jordan brought about important changes in the distribution of what limited independent power is allocated to legislators. The Islamic Action Front (IAF), the Muslim Brotherhood’s affiliated movement in Jordan, won 31 out of 138 seats in the legislature, tripling its numbers and making it the largest opposition group in the country by seat share.
The IAF’s gains in the Jordanian elections have been widely interpreted as a reaction by the Jordanian public to the ongoing war in Gaza. This is not false, but does assume an overly simplistic linkage between this regional conflict and domestic support for Islamist opposition. One does not inevitably follow from another, due to some supposed co-religionist ties between Muslims in Jordan and Gaza. Instead, following the start of the conflict, the IAF deftly positioned itself as supporting an end to the Jordanian government’s peace treaty with Israel and promoted itself as the key protector of Jordan against Israeli aggression – contrasting itself with the government, which has suppressed pro-Palestine protests over the past year. In other words, the IAF’s mobilisation strategy in the face of these unexpected regional events also played a key role in its success.
In summary, elections in the Middle East, like in much (if not all) of the world, exist in a complex grey zone between procedurally “free and fair” in accordance with democratic ideals and mere “sham”. In places like Iran and Jordan, electoral politics are contentious, competitive, and they produce unexpected results that, while not overthrowing autocratic regimes outright, force them to recalibrate their balance of cooptative and coercive strategies.
Sources: Perspective Monde (sources: The Economist, Highcharts.com [map], © Natural Earth); Our World in Data; Wikipedia. Map produced by Whybe.
GRAPH: Increase in the Number of Elections (Legislative and Presidential) since 1800
Source: Wikipedia
BOX: For or Against Electronic Voting?
The elections in Venezuela on 28 July 2024 added fuel to an ongoing debate: for or against electronic voting? Technology is becoming increasingly important in the organisation of elections: for the compilation and purging of voter lists, the planning of polling stations, the sending of results and the counting of votes. While there is agreement on the advantages of its use for these tasks, electronic voting remains controversial: those in favour point out that it brings speed (fast counting) and efficiency (the procedure reduces the incidence of invalidated votes due to errors). Opponents warn that legal security is at stake in terms of the secrecy of the vote (voters often need help to use the machines), transparency is lost (anyone can supervise the paper count but specialised knowledge is needed to understand how the machine works) and it generates dependence on the private sector (which takes over the logistics for large sums of money).
In Latin America, some countries have electronic voting systems (Brazil, Venezuela) or have implemented pilot programmes (Mexico), while others maintain the paper ballot (Argentina, Uruguay). Regardless of the system, allegations of fraud have become part of the electoral strategy of some leaders such as Donald Trump in the United States, Jair Bolsonaro in Brazil (both with electronic voting) or Keiko Fujimori in Peru (paper ballot). In none of them has it been judicially proven. In any case, the transparency and “auditability” of the electoral system becomes central.
Source: Yanina Welp, “El voto electrónico venezolano”, El Universal, 21 August 2024.
BOX: What are the different voting systems?
There are three voting systems: majority, proportional and mixed. Voting may be direct (as in the presidential election) or indirect (as in the senatorial election). They may comprise a single round or several rounds:
- Majority systems are the oldest: the winner of the election takes all the seats at stake. This is known as “first past the post”. These elections make it easier to create a stable and coherent majority to govern, at the risk of under-representing minority opinions. They also guarantee a close link between elected representatives and voters. They may be single-member (a single seat to be filled) or multi-member (several seats);
- In proportional representation systems, the seats are distributed between the various candidates in proportion to the votes obtained. Proportional systems developed in the 20th century: Belgium was the first country to introduce proportional representation for its parliamentary elections (1899), followed by Finland (1906), Denmark (1915), the Netherlands (1917) and Germany (1919). These systems ensure better representation of the various currents of opinion, at the risk of complicating the emergence of a governing majority and strengthening the influence of political parties;
- Mixed systems combine the two systems: for the same election, some candidates are elected under the majority system (in small constituencies) and others under the proportional system (in larger constituencies). This is the case, for example, with municipal elections in France: the majority system applies in municipalities with fewer than 1,000 inhabitants, and the proportional system in municipalities with 1,000 inhabitants or more.
Source: Mathieu Mugnier, “La diversité des modes de scrutin”, Vie publique, 23 October 2024.